Leadership and Progress

It is humbling to have the President do the first act. But it's more than a bit daunting to do the follow up. I now know what they mean by a hard act to follow.

It is a great honor to deliver this talk before this distinguished audience. I am grateful to many people, my wife Marilyn, my colleagues at Carnegie Mellon and AEI, Chris DeMuth, an extraordinary, leader, friend, and mentor, and the trustees and advisers of AEI who have chosen me for this honor.

I have special pride and pleasure at being the first to present a lecture that honors Irving Kristol, a great social scientist, a great patriot, and a great defender of liberty. And I am particularly pleased to celebrate AEI's 60th anniversary. May it continue as a great defender of liberty and progress.

It is almost sixty years since the end of World War II, the effective beginning of the Pax Americana, a great experiment to reshape the world's institutional structure, to prevent reoccurrence of major wars and economic depression and to extend liberty to places and people where it had never been known. Sixty years is a long time in the life of a nation, more than a quarter of our history, and sufficient time to assess the main domestic and international achievements and failures of U.S. leadership. If we listen to the critics, we might conclude that the gains have been modest, the failures large, and the future clouded by environmental degradation, population explosion, nuclear proliferation, rising anti-Americanism and anti-globalization. This would be a wrong conclusion.

The late, great economist Jacob Viner taught that forecasters do as well as human beings can except for those who remain silent. There are always unforeseen events that change outcomes in fundamental and unexpected ways. A story makes this point sharply. Odin, the Norse god, asked his adversary how he could safeguard his kingdom. The adversary agreed to tell him if Odin would give him one of his eyes. Odin agreed and surrendered his eye, whereupon he learned the great secret: "Watch with both eyes."

Looking back a century in the United States, the average person earned less than $500 a year, a dentist $2500, a mechanical engineer about $5000. Pneumonia was the leading cause of death. In the next century the United States moved from one among many countries to a position of pre-eminence. At the end of World War II, it could design the institutions that shaped the postwar economic order.

The same Jacob Viner, writing in 1944, described United States' objectives for international economic relations embodied in legislation ratifying the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, and the Bretton Woods Agreement establishing the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank. "Trade barriers will be as moderate and nondiscriminating as government and peoples . . . can be persuaded to make them; . . . currencies will be freely convertible into each other; . . . long-term capital will move from capital-rich to capital-poor countries; . . . abundant scope will be preserved for the exercise in the international field of competitive enterprise." Viner (1944, 53) We achieved much of that program.

Soon after these new rules of the Pax Americana were in place, the beginning of the cold war required military preparedness, heavy expenditures for developing and producing armaments, maintenance of a large standing army, and development of a system of alliances to share some of the costs and to mark the geographical limits beyond which Soviet expansion would risk war.

Only a few years before the Soviet Union collapsed, some analysts and historians saw only failure. A popular book by historian Paul Kennedy (1987) warned that the Reagan tax cuts and "imperial overstretch" caused budget deficits that would destroy American power and end American influence. Walter Russell Mead wrote in 1987: "The foreign position of the United States decayed rapidly during Reagan's tenure, reflecting a continuing erosion of the economic structure of the American Empire." Mead (1987, 200) Mead added: "It was unlikely that future British prime ministers, of any party, would court political disaster by cooperating too closely with the United States." (202) At home, Mead found "the record was even more dismal." (202)

Viner was right about forecasts, at least these forecasts. It is probably a good thing that prime ministers and presidents don't read such books. Within less than a decade after the books appeared, the complaint had changed. America was now to be feared as the hyper-power militarily, economically and in producing popular culture. It is well to recall that French complaints began before there was a Bush administration or a possible war in Iraq.

I use these forecasts to suggest that the well-known analysts who made them looked at foreign and domestic events through the filter of an inappropriate and invalid set of ideas that led them into error. They overlooked the significant differences that made the postwar years very different from the interwar years. They disregarded very relevant facts that could have corrected the errors. One of the principal facts of the postwar years was well known long before they wrote. These years saw an enormous change in living standards and extraordinary economic and social progress around the world. In the United States, since 1945 per capita income in constant dollars tripled from a level about equal to current Portugal or Ireland to $25,000. A sustained annual rate of increase of less than 2% that produced this progress compares to an annual average of nearly 5.5% in Hong Kong and Singapore in the 1980s and 8 percent in Japan during its high growth period.

The Pax Americana worked extremely well. During the postwar years, more people in more countries increased their living standards by larger amounts than in any period in recorded history. Progress was not limited to incomes. Standards of health, education, and life expectancy improved. Infant mortality declined. Popularly elected governments took root in countries that had never experienced popular sovereignty. Freedom and liberty expanded as never before. This impressive performance owes much to the aspirations and efforts of the multitudes struggling up from poverty and tyranny. Those aspirations seem to exist everywhere. They were not discovered in the postwar years or missing in the interwar years. In the United States, Canada, Western Europe and Australia people have struggled for two centuries to improve their own and their children's lives and to extend liberty.

Two institutional changes, working together, explain much of the difference between postwar and previous experience. One is the spread of capitalism, joining the market system to property rights and the rule of law. The other is the Pax Americana. Let's consider the role of each.

Capitalism and the Market System

Until the nineteenth century, growth was slow and for long periods non-existent. It was only after the beginning of modern capitalism, democratic capitalism, that growth in living standards, increased longevity, improved health care and education could be purchased with the proceeds of economic development. Social and economic progress came to be the norm, the expected result. But this expectation became the norm only where countries accepted capitalist methods, property rights and open trading arrangements.

Postwar experience offers many comparisons between countries that adopted capitalism and the market system and those that did not. Three provide experimental evidence that is as good as we are likely to find in the social sciences. We can hold constant the history, culture, and traditions and observe the outcome after thirty, forty or fifty years of capitalism or socialism in the two Germanys, the two Koreas, and in China and the Chinese diaspora in Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore.

In each of these comparisons, culture, language, and traditions are the same. Outcomes are markedly different. The countries with capitalist institutions and the market system grew richer; the others faltered or went backward. A South Korean now lives on an average income about equal to average incomes in the United States in 1945. His North Korean cousin, if he manages to survive, exists by eating roots and grass. My colleague Nick Eberstadt points out how much diet and living standards matter: seven-year-old South Korean boys are 8 inches taller than North Korean boys. Many of the Hong Kong Chinese escaped from mainland China. By the mid 1990s, the average income in Hong Kong was more than 30 times the income on the mainland and this a decade after the Chinese government accepted a limited market system and began to grow.

For those who choose to see, there is much to see. Going south a few miles from San Diego shows the remarkable difference between the outcomes produced under democratic capitalism, the market system, and the rule of law. Within the United States, we see that success is not limited to one ethnic group, one culture, one race, or one sex. Instead of the decline predicted by Paul Kennedy, Walter Mead and many others, the United States economy after 1982 experienced two of the longest periods of sustained growth in our history punctuated by two mild recessions. Per capita income increased 50 percent from 1980 to 2001. For the first time since the early 1950s, the gap widened between our average income and average incomes in Western Europe and Japan. It was no longer true that the Europeans could have their welfare system and narrow the gap in per capita income with the United States as they chose to do from the 1950s to the 1980s. Now they have to choose between redistribution and higher living standards. They have started to wrestle with that challenge. The outcome is unclear.

Critics point out that the spread of capitalism benefits many, but some are left behind. This claim has now become the roar of the anti-globalists and the demonstrators at international meetings. A glaring problem with such comparisons is that many countries are not part of the global system. They do not adopt capitalist methods and are not open to trade. It is a mistake to blame globalization for the poverty found in countries that do not join the system.

Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1993) studied convergence of countries' living standards. Countries that open their economies and educate their children grow faster than developed countries. They close the gap in living standards.

One recent study finds that poor countries that open to trade have grown twice as fast as rich countries for the past twenty years. As a result poverty has fallen and global income inequality is at the lowest level in a century. Bhalla, (2002 as quoted in IMF 2002, 335) Another study finds that income inequality across countries has fallen since about 1980 and is now below the 1950 level. Williamson (2002, 7). Openness to trade is a principal reason for the rapid growth and declining poverty of developing countries, (ibid., 9). Dollar and Kraay (2000) showed that in countries with fiscal discipline, the rule of law, and low inflation, the benefit of growth for the poor is most certain.

The commitment to freer trade in the Pax Americana gave developing countries the opportunity to realize these gains. Many of the poorest countries are in the Middle East and Sub-Saharan Africa, areas that have not joined the global market by opening their economies to trade and to new technologies and opportunities. These countries have 70% of all major conflicts and casualties and slower growth than most other regions. The UN's recent Arab Development Report attributes these failings to lack of freedom and the low quality of education in Arab schools. Greater freedom would contribute to higher living standards by opening the economy, strengthening the market system and the rule of law.

Not everyone benefits, and all benefits are not immediate. But democratic capitalism, the market system, and an economy open to trade and exchange give opportunities to individuals. Boris Yeltsin expressed this well:

"A great power is a self-reliant and talented people with initiative. . . . And the sole measure of the greatness of our Motherland is the extent to which each citizen of Russia is free, healthy, educated and happy." (Quoted in Aron 2002, 8)

The Pax Americana

Not all market economies prosper. The difference between countries or periods depends greatly on the presence or absence of internal and external institutions that produce stability and the willingness of countries to join the international system and make the internal reforms that permit the market to function well. Accepting the rule of law, fiscal discipline, openness to trade, and private property are key elements.

Countries acting alone cannot produce global stability. The Pax Americana offered global political stability, the defense of common interests, rules for trade and payments, and a general disposition to rely on markets and market processes to allocate resources and to establish a system of human rights and liberty.

This system was not perfect. United States leadership was not always wise or well thought out. Sometimes avoidably, sometimes unavoidably, mistakes were made by the United States, by its adversaries and its allies. Nevertheless, the United States took the lead in providing political stability, rules for freer trade, and international financial stability. It organized many countries into alliances and encouraged its allies and others to gain from trade by adopting rules and peaceful mechanisms for resolving disputes. These arrangements provided benefits to all who joined and many who participated. Economists call arrangements of this kind public goods because, unlike private goods, the benefits are not limited to the producer or a single user. Many can share.

Defense is an example. The European countries acting alone could not expect to defend themselves against an attack by the Soviet Union. The United States could mount a credible defense that gained strength from European support. The United States invested heavily not just in mounting defense but in developing military technology. Europeans knowing that they would be defended could give less than proportional effort. They were the classic free riders. They did not shirk responsibility, but they limited their commitment to a smaller share than the United States of total spending on military weapons, manpower, and the development of weapons systems and technology.

These expenditures and the willingness to use force or the threat of force in Greece, Turkey, and Iran initially, in Korea and Vietnam later, and at other times and places made the commitment credible. Scholars can debate whether all these actions were necessary, wise, or well thought out. That they contributed to decades of political stability is not debatable. And by the late 1980s, they helped to end the cold war. The principal adversary and all but a few of its satraps gave up the conflict. Many former adversaries joined the market system and, acknowledging the superiority of democratic capitalism, began to establish political and economic systems and institutions modeled on western norms.

The trade and financial arrangements created under American leadership contributed to growth and economic expansion. Trade rules permitted countries to choose a strategy of export led growth. That strategy remains feasible only if other countries permit import led consumption. To get this system started, the United States led the way to more open markets for imports and permitted countries to discriminate against its exports. Later, it promoted a system of trade preferences--the General System of Preferences--that continues to offer considerable advantage to developing countries.

Political stability permitted many new or developing countries to curtail spending on defense and devote their resources to investment, economic growth, and raising living standards. Political stability also meant that merchants could travel more freely to many parts of the world, a benefit that wars and terrorism vitiate.

The third key element is financial stability. The initial effort to establish a dollar-based system of fixed exchange rates could not survive the inflationary policies used to finance the Vietnam War abroad and the Great Society at home. More than a decade of inflation and disinflation followed in the major developed countries and many developing countries. The Bretton Woods system failed to achieve financial or price stability. Nevertheless, the market economies avoided the disastrous experience of the interwar period.

The United States did not organize these successful institutions on its own. It exercised leadership both in organizing the postwar world and in adjusting to changing political and economic events. It did not always act alone. It led several successful coalitions. It paid a price in lives, resources, and money, but it achieved unparalleled success for itself, its allies, developing countries that joined the market system and friends of liberty everywhere.

The reader of today's newspapers and journals of opinion must find strange this story of remarkable achievement, of sacrifice by the American public to defeat the adversaries of liberty and to increase living standards for all who chose to participate in its global system. The regular fare of the writers of these journals is criticism of globalization. United States policy is called unilateral, and the United States is castigated for pursuing its interests and promoting liberty in its own way.

Unilateralism

What should one make of the charge of unilateralism? The word suggests different purposes, that what the United States sees as its policy interest, broadly or narrowly defined, differs from what others see as in their interest. There is some truth to this claim of different purposes, but stopping there misses the source of these differences and how they are likely to evolve. Stopping with a complaint about unilateralism also misleads the public into thinking that, if we would change to a more multilateral policy, tensions between Europe and the United States would greatly diminish or even vanish. That seems unlikely.

An example shows how facile is the claim that United States policy pursues its own, narrowly defined, unilateral interest. The confrontation with Iraq over weapons of mass destruction protects Europe as it does the United States. The United States does not gather all the gains from successful confrontation, though it will pay the largest share of the costs. U.S. policy creates a classic public good. A more peaceful world benefits the Europeans, including those governments who complain most about our actions and policies.

I believe that one reason for reluctance in several European countries to join us is the opportunity to be free riders. Europe is not monolithic. It is not even united on these issues. Several countries support our policies and actions but can offer little assistance. They are free riders. Others could offer assistance but want to exercise control. France is the leader of this group. Then there is Britain, willing to help us supply public goods.

A frequent explanation attributes many of the differences to values. It is certainly true that many European journalists and politicians are disturbed by the moral certitude with which some U.S. presidents have condemned their adversaries as evil. Differences in values are not new. They existed during the cold war, so they cannot explain the increased hostility that now characterizes relations with France and Germany. I will offer three reasons that I believe are more relevant.

First, like all public goods, defense invites free riders who can gain the common benefit without sharing in the cost. Once the threat of Soviet tanks and troops pouring through the Fulda Gap disappeared, European interest in common defense weakened. Military spending, troop strength, weapons systems, and preparedness declined. Germany spends on defense about half of what the U.S. spends relative to GDP. The United States spends more on defense than the next ten largest spenders. This spending protects others as well as us.

Britain is the outlier that requires explanation. Others are willing to depend on U.S. defense forces to protect them, while carping that we are too belligerent, too passive, too warlike, or lacking in strategic vision. All of these complaints, and others, were voiced before the Kosovo engagement, when Europeans showed themselves incapable of agreeing on and executing a policy to defend their region from renewed tyranny. They behaved as free riders do, waiting for the United States to supply the public good.

Britain and France take polar positions. Even before the end of the cold war, French policy aimed at creating a distinctly European policy led by France and supported by Germany. British governments have opposed as best they can a European system dominated by France and Germany, free riding on American defense and foreign policy efforts outside of Europe. It has not been averse to rewarding itself by pursuing its commercial interests even if they support hostile governments. British governments have opposed the French vision and supported a strong U.S. influence in NATO and in Europe to counter it.

Second, the Middle East poses a special problem for principal European countries. A large and growing part of the population in France and Germany recently came from the Middle East or North Africa. They have friends and relatives in Muslim countries. Their presence in these countries makes a large voting bloc, and a noisy non-voting bloc, which regards assistance to Palestinians and other Muslims as a high priority issue. Further, Germany and France have not developed arrangements for integrating recent immigrants as full participants in their economic and political life. Many are restless, chafing at their status. Without major changes, this problem will grow over time as the Muslim proportion of the European population rises. This is a problem we know well from our own past experience.

Third for the French government and some others, the attractive alternative is not to match U.S. spending on defense but to control the way in which that spending is used. By demanding a large role for the U.N. Security Council in reaching decisions, France and Russia increase their role relative to ours. If we are going to defend them, along with ourselves, they want to control the conditions. If we resist, we are accused of unilateralism, a claim that gains in importance because of the vocal support it receives in the United States. These tactics are not limited to defense. France, particularly, has used international pressure to impose large costs on the United States.

Those who call for an end to American unilateralism hark back to an earlier period in which unilateralism was absent. When would that have been? Lord Skidelsky's biography of Lord Keynes describes the negotiations in the 1940s over the start of the postwar order. "Britain would accept the obligations of multilateralism only if guaranteed a large credit line to the United States." Skidelsky (2001, 383) In August 1945, President Truman shocked the British, French, and others by canceling lend lease shipments without prior warning. In 1962, Germany and France threatened to convert their dollars into gold to pressure President Kennedy into changing his policy toward Europe. Kennedy threatened to remove U.S. troops from Europe in response. This occurred at a time when the United States not only defended these countries but permitted them to discriminate in trade against U.S. exports. And there are many other examples, including French withdrawal of its troops from NATO.

There is nothing new about countries placing their own interest first. After returning from negotiations in Europe in 1962, Board of Governors Chairman William McChesney Martin wrote to President Kennedy: "This is a tough, rough mean gang. And there is very little altruism." (Kennedy 2001, 469) In the past, U.S. leadership was often the force that drove the alliance together. What has changed most is not the discovery of self-interest; it is that with the end of the cold war, European governments have greater opportunity to be free riders and a reduced need to accept U.S. leadership and U.S. response to the change. This has reshaped the alliance, and it will continue to do so, thereby changing a main building block of political stability or even ending the alliance. We should try to work with them, but we should expect continued friction.

Trade and Finance

The two remaining pillars of the Pax Americana were rules for trade and finance. The challenge here is to reshape the system in a way that recognizes the progress that has been made and the changed relations after the end of the cold war.

Although criticized regularly by anti-globalization activists, the benefits of tariff reduction and rules for trade are well and repeatedly documented. As many have noted, one need only compare changes in living standards in countries that opened their economies to those that have not. Barro (1991), Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1993), Dollar and Kraay (2000) inter alia. The greater challenges now are to reduce the remaining tariffs, including developed country tariffs on textiles and foodstuffs, bring the many separate trading blocs into a global trading system, find more effective means of identifying and reducing non-tariff barriers, and develop incentives that encourage corrupt, oligarchic governments to open their economies and permit development to occur. The command and control system at the blundering World Bank just will not do. If the major countries want to encourage economic development in the poorest countries, they will reduce their tariffs on agriculture and textile imports and reform or replace the World Bank.

The problem of globalization is to rid the system of impediments to more open exchange arrangements. The distinguished economist Paul Samuelson tells about being challenged by a famous physical scientist to offer one proposition in economics that is not obviously true. Samuelson cited the gains from trade--the proposition that both parties to a trade gain. This is one source of the gain from opening economies, from globalizing. Anyone who looks at the evidence with an unbiased and dispassionate eye will find that though the gains do not go equally to everyone, the gains are greater and more widely distributed than under any other economic system. That is why our former adversaries have adopted many of our institutions. They have not been hoodwinked or coerced. They have recognized what anti-globalists refuse to see.

A pressing issue is whether present trade institutions need to be changed. The three most serious problems are the proliferation of bilateral trade agreements, the difficulty of extending agreements to non-tariff barriers, and the rising demands for protection brought by labor unions, farm, and environmental groups. Bilateral agreements often harm third parties by shifting trade patterns against them. A way must be found to convert bilateral to multilateral agreements within a reasonable period. This would require asking NAFTA and the EU, for example, to reduce external tariffs. One country's non-tariff barrier can be another country's health or safety shield. Overcoming these barriers becomes difficult unless an agency like the World Trade Organization can make quasi-judicial rulings. Allowing such rulings may override local laws and sovereignty. This problem is familiar from quarrels with the Europeans over taxation, beef, and biological engineering of foodstuffs and animal feed.

The use of sanctions to compensate for violations of trade rules is a lesser, but not unimportant, problem. Under current rules, countries can impose tariffs on imports as compensation for a foreign government's trade restrictions. This allows the injured country to reduce selected imports by raising the prices paid by domestic users. Surely there is a better way to enforce rules than to penalize others by penalizing oneself.

The central issues about the future of the World Trade Organization are whether the current system has provided most of the benefits it is likely to bring and whether the costs of additional agreements now exceed potential benefits. Both GATT and WTO found it impossible to reduce remaining tariffs on raw material and agricultural exports from emerging countries. Negotiations affecting service industries often involve performance standards that are very difficult to negotiate, even more difficult to make precise, and therefore unlikely to be enforced effectively. WTO judgments may override local law or require changes that countries are reluctant to enforce. It seems right to ask whether the large benefits that have been achieved exhausted the benefits likely to be obtained in the future. A new strategy is needed.

A major challenge is to find a new role for the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank that provides net social benefits. Two decades of intermittent crises in Latin America, Mexico, East Asia, Brazil, Argentina, Russia, and elsewhere raise doubts about the ability of present arrangements to maintain stability and growth. A long history of reduced living standards in client countries and a high failure rate of World Bank programs in poor countries suggest that the World Bank has failed the test. It is costly, bureaucratic and, much too often, ineffective.

In principle the IMF could provide two public goods if properly restructured. It could reduce the risk of global financial crises, provide information and accounting and financial standards that reduce costs of learning about countries' prospects. Better information improves markets by permitting transactors to make more informed choices. One possible benefit would be reduced herd-like behavior by lenders to these countries.

The IMF has an advantage in obtaining information because it has programs in many countries and issues regular reports on problems and prospects. The IMF has made significant improvements in the quality and quantity of information it releases, but much more could be done to improve the quality and timeliness of country data. Congressman Saxton and the Congressional Joint Economic Committee have taken a leading role in demanding better information and reform of IMF practices. They should continue to do so.

The IMF's most important tasks are crisis prevention and amelioration. In the past it has interpreted this responsibility broadly to include requiring policy decisions in many areas unrelated to economic stability. Its achievements have been limited. Crises have become larger and more frequent. Countries promise much but often change very little. Governments understand that the IMF continues to lend at subsidized rates even if the country fails to meet agreed conditions. Governments recognize that the IMF's management has in the past been more reluctant than the borrowing government to acknowledge that a program failed to achieve its objectives.

The United States has not helped the IMF to restructure its activities. Instead of lending to all countries with problems, it should limit its role to preventing crises from spreading to neighboring countries, trading partners, and innocent bystanders. Instead of lengthy negotiations to extract promises of reform, it should not lend to countries that have not adopted and maintained some specified policies that enhance stability. If there is a threat of a spreading crisis, the IMF should help potential victims, not the culprit.

Instituting these changes would replace the command and control system, based on a Washington consensus, with incentives for the country to choose and adopt stabilizing policies. Governments could explain to voters and legislators that reforms would reduce country risk, lowering interest rates. Reformed borrowers would obtain more credit from the market at lower cost, facilitating economic and social development. The IMF would be free to set standards and allow countries to implement the standards in their own way. Lenders would know the countries that adopted the standards and those that did not. They would know also that if they lent to countries that had not reformed, they should expect to lose in a crisis. IMF loans would not bail them out.

Some of these steps are in process. The new management at the IMF has responded to criticism with less command and control and more attention to local control. Alas, less has been done to narrow the IMF's focus from managing many developing countries to the more urgent task of preventing multilateral crises by giving countries greater incentives to reform.

The World Bank poses a more difficult problem because, in practice, the nature of the public good it provides is less clear. Originally one of the Bank's main purposes was to offset a claimed market reluctance to lend to developing countries. For the past twenty years or longer, many of the problems in developing countries arose because the country and its residents attracted not too little but too much foreign lending, especially too much short-term, renewable lending. The development banks and the IMF paid too little attention to the risky situations they helped to create, and lenders learned to expect bailouts or support when problems developed, so they continued this unstable system.

If the World Bank were less bureaucratic, more focused, and had a better record of accomplishment; it might be possible to learn what it does more efficiently than the private sector. An independent performance evaluation should be mandatory. Based on that review, the Bank should be reorganized and told to limit its activities to programs where it can provide what the market does not provide. I believe that four activities would remain.

First, the Bank's staff are experts on many technical problems faced by developing countries. The Bank should rent this expertise to countries at a subsidized price.

Second, the development banks can support programs to improve the quality of life for people in poor countries with inefficient or corrupt governments. Providing potable water and sanitation or improving health care are examples. The International Financial Institution Advisory Commission proposed monitored grants in place of loans to improve prospects that the benefits would be achieved. The O'Neill Treasury succeeded after much effort to get agreement from the Bank and other countries to shift part of its subsidized loans to monitored grants. If the program is implemented correctly, it will improve the lot of the poorest among us.

Third, the Bank can get countries in a region to agree on and implement environmental safeguards, disease eradication or reduction and similar regional programs with larger social benefits than the costs of providing them. Malaria, AIDS, measles, and other diseases are examples.

Fourth, the most difficult of all is to develop incentives within countries for sustained structural reforms, including rule of law, protection of private property, reduced corruption, economic stability, democratic accountability, and openness to trade. These reforms cannot be made overnight. They require persistent efforts to develop institutions and habit patterns that differ markedly from traditional ways. Sustained growth depends on these reforms, but the reforms depend on sustained commitment by country governments. A workable set of incentives to maintain progress is badly needed.

Conclusion

When World War II ended, the United States offered to provide rules for trade, an international financial system, development aid, and later political stability enforced by military power. These arrangements permitted much of the world to concentrate on economic and social development with unparalleled success. U.S. leadership promoted postwar progress in many countries, while maintaining peace and eventually defeating its adversaries.

Against this record of unparalleled achievements in market economies is the record of failure by the many experiments that pursued development outside the global system. These failures are not limited to the Soviet Union and its satraps but include much of Africa, India before its reforms, Alan Garcia's Peru, Cuba, the Sandanistas' Nicaragua, and many others.

The end of the cold war weakened the bonds of alliance, permitted governments to become more independent of the United States and weakened the global system. This is clearest in Western Europe, but the change is visible in Japan, Korea, and South America.

With the end of the cold war, increased wealth and the spread of democratic government, new arrangements are called for to provide the public goods that progress requires. All countries have a stake in that progress and in developing or supporting institutions that give incentives for progress. A new Pax Americana, like the old, requires military strength, new rules for trade, and arrangements to maintain financial stability and economic well-being. Success would continue the remarkable progress of the last sixty years. Failure would likely slow this long period of global growth, increased liberty, and human progress. Developing these new arrangements is the major challenge to U.S. leadership as the engine of world progress in the new century.

References

Aron, Leon, (2002). "A Private Hero for a Privatized Country," Washington: American Enterprise Institute, (Summer).

Barro, Robert J., (1991). "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407-43.

Barro, Robert J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. (1992). "Convergence", Journal of Political Economy, 100, 223-51.

Bhalla, Surjit, (2002). Imagine There's No Country's Poverty Inequality and Growth in the Era of Globalization. Washington: Institute for International Economics.

Dollar, David and Kraay, Art, (2000). "Growth Is Good for the Poor," (unpublished) The World Bank.

IMF, (2002). IMF Survey, 31, Washington: International Monetary Fund, (October 21).

Kennedy, John F., (2001). The Presidential Recordings: The Great Crises, Volume 1, July 30-August 1962. J. Naftali, (ed.) New York: Norton.

Kennedy, Paul, (1987). The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York: Random House.

Kristol, Irving, (1978). Two Cheers for Capitalism. New York: Basic Books.

Mead, Walter R., (1987). Mortal Splendor: The American Empire in Transition. Boston: Houghton, Mifflin.

Skidelsky, Robert, (2001). John Maynard Keynes, Volume 3, Fighting for Freedom, 1937-1946. New York: Viking.

Viner, Jacob, (1944). "The Views of Jacob Viner." In International Financial Stabilization. M. Shields (ed.), New York: Irving Trust.

( I am grateful to Christopher DeMuth for helpful comments.)

Allan H. Meltzer is the recipient of AEI's Irving Kristol Award for 2003.

Also Visit
AEIdeas Blog The American Magazine
About the Author

 

Allan H.
Meltzer

What's new on AEI

Holder will regret his refusal to obey the Constitution
image 'Flood Wall Street' climate protesters take aim at their corporate allies
image 3 opportunities for better US-India defense ties
image Is Nicolás Maduro Latin America's new man at the United Nations?
AEI on Facebook
Events Calendar
  • 29
    MON
  • 30
    TUE
  • 01
    WED
  • 02
    THU
  • 03
    FRI
Thursday, October 02, 2014 | 9:00 a.m. – 10:30 a.m.
Campbell Brown talks teacher tenure

We welcome you to join us as Brown shares her perspective on the role of the courts in seeking educational justice and advocating for continued reform.

Event Registration is Closed
Friday, October 03, 2014 | 12:00 p.m. – 1:00 p.m.
Harnessing the power of markets to tackle global poverty: A conversation with Jacqueline Novogratz

AEI welcomes you to this Philanthropic Freedom Project event, in which Novogratz will describe her work investing in early-stage enterprises, what she has learned at the helm of Acumen, and the role entrepreneurship can play in the fight against global poverty.

No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.
No events scheduled this day.