AEI » Latest Content http://www.aei.org American Enterprise Institute: Freedom, Opportunity, Enterprise Mon, 24 Nov 2014 16:11:03 +0000 en-US hourly 1 Education that workshttp://www.aei.org/events/education-works/ http://www.aei.org/events/education-works/#comments Tue, 21 Oct 2014 20:49:30 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=event&p=816541 AEI’s exclusive Vision Talks series convenes America’s leading scholars, thinkers, and practitioners to offer fresh perspectives on key areas of policy and public debate. These talks will be filmed and disseminated as standalone videos, such as Robert Doar’s “What works in helping the poor?” talk.

In the United States, we think of education as the key to equal opportunity. But while spending on education is higher than ever, student achievement — particularly for disadvantaged students — has not kept pace.

Myriad government efforts to improve educational attainment have shown mixed results at best. Is conventional thought on reforming education misguided? Is there a better way to foster excellence? What can parents, educators, and citizens do about it, and how can they make an effective case for change?

Please join us for four concise talks on why America needs to rethink education, what that thinking looks like in practice, and how compelling communication can turn ideas into action.

This event will not be live streamed.

If you have trouble registering, please contact laura.lalinde@aei.org.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/events/education-works/feed/ 0
Interpreting broadband statistics: Frequently asked questionshttp://www.aei.org/publication/interpreting-broadband-statistics-frequently-asked-questions/ http://www.aei.org/publication/interpreting-broadband-statistics-frequently-asked-questions/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 16:00:12 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822297 ...]]]> 1. What is the difference between broadband and the Internet?

The Internet is a global, virtual, or logical “network of networks” that links billions of devices around the world. Broadband, on the other hand, is the high-speed physical network at the edge of the Internet that connects end users to the global system. The most prevalent broadband technologies in the G7 are DSL, cable, fiber, and mobile. Overall, broadband is part of the Internet, but the Internet is more than just broadband.

2. How does the Internet work?

The Internet is 40,000 independently owned and operated networks that connect to each other either directly or through intermediaries, such as transit networks, according to mutually satisfactory terms and conditions. These networks all use the Internet Protocol addressing conventions. Some interconnections are paid – such as when an American ISP uses a transit network to reach other countries – but many are unpaid, such as one American ISP connecting to another. The Internet is administered by multi-stakeholder organizations in which governments play a role but do not dominate.

3. Wired vs. Mobile broadband: how are they the same and how are they different?

Both wired and mobile broadband networks use Internet Protocol and connect to the global Internet at common Internet Exchange Points. But wired and mobile networks run different application mixes and have different technical characteristics.

For instance, mobile networks rely on cell towers, which are part of an existing mobile network. In order to add capacity to mobile networks, operators need to modify tower configurations or, in the worst case scenario, buy spectrum licenses at auction, add additional antennas to each mobile device they sell, and again modify tower configuration. This process is complicated and expensive, and it takes a lot of time to implement. On the plus side, however, the mobile broadband environment is very dynamic and competitive, and it reaches most of us in most of the places we go.

On the other hand, wired networks rely on DSL, cable, FTTP, or other technologies rather than towers. It is easier and far less expensive for wired broadband companies to add capacity to their networks, but they don’t go where we go.

4. Who regulates broadband and what are the options?

Today, broadband companies are regulated to some extent under the FTC and antitrust law, and to some extent under the FCC. The FCC, however, does exercise the same authority over broadband services that it does over telephone services. The FCC is mainly concerned with broadband outcomes for consumers, and it may choose to expand its control should the commissioners believe that current broadband policy does not promote investment, competition, openness, and other political and policy goals.

The FCC could expand its power in three ways: it could reclassify broadband providers under Title II of the Communications Act; issue a broad set of principles that define acceptable and unacceptable practices and ban unacceptable ones on a case-by-case basis through adjudication; or impose anti-discrimination rules without reclassification. Other options for broadband regulation including merging the competition and consumer protection aspects of the FCC and FTC into a single organization, which would in turn regulate broadband companies.

broadband photo 35. Where does the US stand compared to the rest of the world in broadband quality?

Despite inherent challenges in wiring a country as enormous as the US, the country is performing extremely well. Historical data on international broadband speeds shows that the US continually ranks ahead of comparable nations. It is worth noting that the highest-ranking countries in terms of download speed consist of a few tiny, densely-populated nations where Internet use is much lighter in volume terms than it is in the US. Additionally, the US has greater choice of broadband technologies and speeds than most anywhere in the world. The US also has the most extensive build-out of 4G/LTE in the world.

6. How does the US regulatory policy for broadband compare to the rest of the world?

The US and Canada share a similar broadband regulatory framework. Both nations reserve subsidies for research and development, as well as for rural network expansion. They rely mostly on private capital to finance advanced urban systems. The role of government in this framework is to accelerate diffusion of advanced technologies to rural areas.

In contrast, Japan, Germany, and the U.K. have adopted a semi-deregulated regulatory frameworks in which legacy networks such as DLS are price-controlled but advanced fiber networks are not.

Finally, broadband in countries like France and Italy is almost entirely subsidy-dependent. Public investment drives broadband build-out and innovation, and the resulting broadband connections are cheap but low-quality. Additionally, the low sticker price of broadband in these countries does not take into account the enormous tax revenue that funds broadband service in the first place.

broadband photo 27. What effects does competition have on Internet quality? Price?

Contrary to popular belief, the market for broadband is dynamic and competitive. Firms like Comcast, AT&T, Verizon, and others face enormous incentives to invest in R&D and quickly introduce broad, sweeping innovations to the market. These innovations temporarily earn them more customers, higher revenues, and greater market share. However, firms that fall behind risk falling out of the market entirely.

Such competition generates increasingly better connections for consumers. While the cost of providing broadband in the US is inherently greater than costs in smaller, more densely-populated nations, consumers here pay less for more speed and capacity than citizens in comparable European nations.

Additionally, people usually come across several different Internet access points in a given day. For example, you probably have access to wired broadband both at home and at work. Meanwhile, you can simultaneously connect wirelessly on a smartphone or tablet in restaurants, cafes, public spaces, and elsewhere. Consumers are not beholden to any single ISP and can quickly and easily compare quality across services. Ultimately, ISPs compete against each other for overall market share and for shares of a single customer’s time. Consumers have a considerable amount of leverage in this market, which keeps quality high and prices low.

8. How are Internet services like Netflix and Amazon that depend on broadband regulated?

Netflix and Amazon are regulated under the FTC’s antitrust and consumer protection laws. As long as they continue to innovate and operate competitively, Netflix and Amazon are mostly ignored by federal regulators.

9. How profitable are broadband companies compared to: A) content creators; B) “Edge services?”

Averaging returns on invested capital (ROIC) across firms in each sector and then comparing sector averages shows that the edge services sector is most profitable and best protected from competition. Internet edge providers are protected from competition in the sense that their ROIC average consistently exceeds 15 percent, a common benchmark for determining whether a company has a “moat” against competition; these firms have averaged 17.8 percent ROIC over the past five years. In comparison, network service providers consistently earn around 5 percent ROIC.

Internet edge firms have produced 63 percent greater ROIC than content creators and 178 percent greater return than network service providers. There is clearly no factual basis on which to accuse networking companies of being excessively profitable.

10. What’s the next generation of broadband and how do we get there? Apps?

Most likely, the next generation of broadband will be wireless. The US is investing more in mobile and other wireless networks today than in residential wired connections. Wireless is the main focus of innovation in consumer products, and those who rely on wired connections at home are often supplied with more capacity than they need or use. Across the OECD, most of the growth in broadband subscriptions takes place on mobile.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/interpreting-broadband-statistics-frequently-asked-questions/feed/ 0
A pivotal shift in the new Child Care Development and Block Granthttp://www.aei.org/publication/pivotal-shift-new-child-care-development-block-grant/ http://www.aei.org/publication/pivotal-shift-new-child-care-development-block-grant/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 15:48:25 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822307 Last Wednesday, largely overshadowed by the immigration reform debacle, President Obama signed into law a bipartisan bill reauthorizing the Child Care Development and Block Grant Act (CCDBG)—the primary federal grant program providing child care assistance to low- and middle-income working families—just two days after it passed in the Senate with an overwhelming majority of 88 to 1. In an era when signed bills are all too rare, the CCDBG reauthorization isn’t just a signed bill but a good signed bill, with thoughtful new focus on early learning, quality, and transparency.

The most striking aspect of the newly-reauthorized CCDBG is its pivotal shift from viewing child care solely as a babysitting service for working parents to seeing it, too, as a crucial opportunity for young children’s early development and learning. CCDBG’s aim has long been to help lower-income parents—especially mothers—remain employed and off welfare, by ensuring they have safe, affordable care for their children while they’re at work. But a rapidly growing body of scientific research shows that a child’s early years are much more important to learning and brain development than was understood when CCDBG was first written in 1990 and last reauthorized in 1996. And in response to this new knowledge, the bill’s focus has been considerably expanded to providing young children with high quality learning opportunities, while supporting their working parents at the same time.

The new bill heavily stresses child development and learning (neither “development” nor “learning” were even mentioned in the previous bill), now requiring that states establish guidelines for what very young children should know and be able to do at progressive stages of their early development. It puts much stronger emphasis on improving program quality: while not telling states how to define quality, the bill requires that states both come up with their own definition of quality and develop a plan for improving it. “Standards” were barely mentioned in the previous bill, but in this one they’re underscored throughout with respect to program design, quality, safety, licensing, and oversight. The new CCDBG reflects an impressive commitment to maximizing the benefit of child care for the children who are in it.

Finally, the reauthorization includes a notable new stipulation for the federal government itself, mandating that in the coming year the Department of Health and Human Services (which runs both CCDBG and Head Start) work with the Department of Education (which runs several other early education programs) conduct an “interdepartmental review” of all programs for children from ages 0 – 5 and submit a recommendation to Congress for integrating and streamlining them. Those two agencies are hardly known for their close collaboration and, in theory anyway, this approach could lead to big improvements in the quality and combined impact of the federal government’s fragmented early childhood programs. Such reform would be an admirable accomplishment for stakeholders “inside the beltway” and a significant win for America’s most vulnerable young children.

In the meantime, CCDBG’s reauthorization establishes a solid, sensible framework that enables the people closest to children to make decisions for their care, while leaving the major decision-making and implementation power in the hands of the states. Now it’s up to the states to use that power wisely—so parents who have to can work and kids get the early care and education they need to thrive.

Follow AEIdeas on Twitter at @AEIdeas.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/pivotal-shift-new-child-care-development-block-grant/feed/ 0
Obamacare’s three-legged stool of deception regarding employer health planshttp://www.aei.org/publication/obamacares-three-legged-stool-deception-regarding-employer-health-plans/ http://www.aei.org/publication/obamacares-three-legged-stool-deception-regarding-employer-health-plans/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 15:21:15 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822293 ...]]]> Anyone who has listened to the Gruber tapes has heard Prof. Gruber’s repeated references to the “three-legged stool” that forms the core of Obamacare.[1]  However, those who pay close attention to his remarks–variously characterized as “arrogant” (Charles Krauthammer), “ careless” (New York Times), “dumb” (Ezra Klein) “ ill-advised and indefensible” (Times Argus), “offensive” (New York Times), and “stupid” (David Axelrod)–may have detected that Gruber enthusiastically endorses (and Obamacare contains) a more sinister three-legged stool of deception regarding employer health plans.

The first leg is that the Cadillac tax is paid by insurance companies, when in reality it is paid by employees. The second leg is that the Cadillac tax is aimed at “lavish” high cost plans, when in reality it is designed to eventually hit virtually every employer health plan (even those with lower-than-average costs). The third leg is that the Cadillac tax is functionally equivalent to a reform long championed by conservatives: a cap on the tax exclusion for employer-sponsored health insurance.  For reasons explained below, that is the most pernicious deception of all.

This carefully designed three-legged stool of deception was crafted to achieve the greatest deception of all: that Obamacare “would support and sustain the employer-based system, not erode it.”   In fact, Obamacare is designed to slowly but surely erode and eventually eradicate the employer-based health system .

Deception #1: The Cadillac Tax is Paid By Insurance Companies

This is the deception about which Prof. Gruber is most transparent. Several different lecture videos make reference to this tax: the first from from a 2011 lecture on Pioneer Institute for public policy research in Boston, another in January 18, 2012 at the Noblis Innovation and Collaboration Center (Falls Church, VA), another at University of Rhode Island on November 1, 2012 and the third at an October 2013 event at Washington University in St. Louis. In the latter lecture (31:48), he gleefully notes that “the American voters are too stupid to know the difference” between a 40% excise tax on employer-provided health benefits and the identical tax levied on health insurers. For reasons he discusses earlier in that tape, the former would have been perceived as “taxing my health benefits” (which would have incited fierce opposition) whereas the designers firmly believed that the latter would be perceived as being paid by the very same big bad insurance companies that had been repeatedly vilified by President ObamaKathleen SebeliusNancy Pelosi and progessive bloggers throughout the debate over health reform.  

Ezra Klein acknowledges quite clearly what was going on: “That [the Cadillac tax on insurers] was a purely political move that was meant to slightly obscure what the law was really doing. Obama had run against Sen. John McCain’s plan to cap the employer deduction, and he couldn’t propose the exact same policy.[2] And Democrats preferred the optics of taxing insurers rather than taxing employers, even though, in the end, workers would pay in either scenario. It was a perfectly transparent political ploy that slightly degraded the underlying policy.”

But why does this seemingly minor subterfuge matter?  As Forbes opinion editor Avik Roy has pointed out: “This allowed President Obama and his allies to falsely claim that Obamacare wouldn’t increase taxes on the middle class, despite the fact that the Cadillac tax clearly affects middle-income Americans, especially unionized industrial laborers.  This was a direct violation of Senator Obama’s 2008 vow not to raise middle-class taxes. “I can make a firm pledge,” said Obama on September 12, 2008. “Under my plan, no family making less than $250,000 a year will see any form of tax increase. Not your income tax, not your payroll tax, not your capital gains taxes, not any of your taxes.”

In short, Obamacare was deliberately crafted to break that “no new taxes on the middle class” pledge by relying on the “stupidity” of the American voter not to notice.[3]  This was not an inadvertent “whoops” unintended consequence of a hastily-put-together-poorly-drafted law: it was deliberate deception well understood by all the cooks who baked this awful cake.

Deception #2: The Cadillac Tax is Aimed Only at “Lavish” High Cost Plans

The very name “Cadillac” tax connotes that it is aimed at gold-plated rather than run-of-the-mill health insurance plans. Prof. Gruber’s comic book explanation of Obamacare elaborates: “As for the Cadillac tax, it is designed to keep people from loading up on unnecessary health care as a tax write-off….What it will do is cut into the one-third of unnecessary care that we waste” (p. 136).  In his 2013 video (31:07), he states “for insurance above a certain level, a very high level, then we tax extra above that” (emphasis added).

Even the president weighed in: as summarized by CNN’s Jake Tapper,

at a town hall meeting on health care on July 23, 2009 in Shaker Heights, Ohio, Obama explained that the thinking of the Cadillac tax was to target plans that spend unnecessarily and excessively, thus driving up health care costs, such as a $25,000 plan, ‘so one that’s a lot more expensive and a lot fancier than the one that even members of Congress get.’ The thinking, Obama explained, was that ‘maybe at that point what you should do is you should sort of cap the exclusion, the tax deduction that is available, so that we’re discouraging these really fancy plans that end up driving up costs’” (emphasis added).

To be sure, the Cadillac tax is aimed at the highest cost plans, but only initially. But as Gruber himself states (2:53 in this clip assembled by Jake Tapper): ”What that means is a tax that starts by only taxing about the top eight percent of health insurance plans, essentially amounts over the next 20 years to basically getting rid of the employer exclusion-provided health insurance. This was the only political way we were ever going to take on what is one of the worst public policies in America” (emphasis added). More concretely:

  • Tevi Troy and Mark Wilson estimate that “by 2031 the cost of the average family health-care plan is expected to hit the excise-tax threshold.”
  • But the adverse impact could play out much more rapidly than that 2031 figure might imply. Bradley Herring, a health economist at Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, estimates that as many as 75 percent of plans could be affected by the tax just in the next decade.
  • A recent Towers Watson survey of employers had an even more bleak forecast, with 82% of employers expecting to hit the Cadillac tax threshold by 2023.

In short, what was advertised as a 40% tax on a small number of egregiously high cost employer-provided health plans will–by design–morph into a 40% tax on all employer-sponsored coverage! [To avoid any confusion: the 40% excise tax is applied to the amount of the employee benefit that exceeds the tax threshold, not the entire cost of an employer's health plan; my point is that eventually all employer-sponsored health benefits would see at least a portion of their costs subjected to the 40% tax].

This again was literally the opposite of what the president pledged. In the Shaker Heights town meeting, the president had stated:

what I said and I’ve taken off the table would be the idea that you just described, which would be that you would actually provide — you would eliminate the tax deduction that employers get for providing you with health insurance, because, frankly, a lot of employers then would stop providing health care, and we’d probably see more people lose their health insurance than currently have it. And that’s not obviously our objective in reform

Note that none of what President Obama said in those remarks is in dispute. Indeed, in 2010, Gruber himself estimated that elimination of the tax exclusion would result in 15 million fewer people getting employer-sponsored coverage, with an attendant rise in the number of uninsured by 11 million. Admittedly, the Shaker Heights remarks were made 5 months before the Senate passed the plan that ultimately would be signed into law by the president. But was the president truly that badly informed about the contents of his own health law that he would sign a bill that did the exact opposite of what he pledged?  Or was he engaging in flagrant deception knowing that (in Gruber’s words) “this was the only political way we were ever going to take on what is one of the worst public policies in America”?  You be the judge.

Deception #3: The Cadillac Tax is Functionally Equivalent to Capping (or Eliminating) the Tax Exclusion

Ezra Klein to this day continues to promote this canard: “Gruber was rightly pissed off when Democrats moved from the clean, simple solution of capping the deduction permitted for employer-based health care to the more complex, but functionally similar, excise-tax on high-cost health plans” (emphasis added).  Of course, Gruber’s anger evidently dissipated rather quickly. By 2013, we see him enthusiastically explaining that “The Cadillac tax is a great thing. It puts an end to this incredibly inefficient structure [the employer tax exclusion] that induces excess medical spending” (31:55).

But there’s a rather sizable difference between imposing a 40% excise tax on every single health plan provided by employers and a policy that simply caps (or even eliminates) the tax exclusion from those same policies.  Remember that the 40% excise tax does not eliminate the awful tax exclusion that motivates the Cadillac tax. Instead, it merely “cancels” or “offsets” the subsidy (or in terms of other policy debates, serves as a “ clawback” to reduce or eliminate that subsidy).

The easiest way to understand this is to compare the Cadillac tax to capping the tax exclusion at the identical dollar threshold used to determine whether a plan is subject to the Cadillac tax. Consider 2 California workers, one earning $10 an hour and the other earning $50. The first worker does not have enough income to pay any federal income tax, so the marginal tax rate on the last dollar earned is only 17.3%, consisting of 15.3% for Social Security and 2% for California income taxes.[4]  Thus, by not taxing that worker’s health benefits as income, the tax exclusion essentially provides a 17.3% discount or subsidy.  The second worker faces a marginal tax rate of 52.6%, consisting of 28% for federal income taxes, another 9.3% for California income taxes and 15.3% for Social Security. This worker receives a 52.6% savings (subsidy) on whatever premiums are paid for employer-sponsored coverage. This upside-down subsidy structure clearly is very offensive to Jon Gruber (listen to the tapes!) and is part of the motivation that conservative health reformers have instead advocated for some sort of standardized tax credits to replace the exclusion.

But the Cadillac tax does not eliminate this unfairness!  The current tax exclusion remains in full force for the full amount of employer-provided coverage costs. The excise tax effectively subtracts 40% from whatever subsidy a worker is getting–but only for the component of costs that exceeds the Cadillac tax threshold. Thus, if both illustrative workers are enrolled in health plans costing $12,200 for individual coverage, $2,000 would be subject to the Cadillac tax of 40%. Thus, the low-wage worker would get a subsidy of $2111 (17.3% x $12,200) minus $800, for a net of $1,311 and the high-wage worker would get a subsidy of $6417 (52.6% x $12,200) minus $800, for a net of $5,617. Sound fair to you?

Obviously, as the amount of premiums subject to the excise tax rises, there will come a cross-over point for the low-wage worker who eventually would pay a tax penalty for the privilege of retaining employer-provided health coverage. But that point never comes for the high-wage worker!  That is, even if the inflation adjuster got us to a point where virtually the entire premium were subject to the excise tax, the high-wage work still would enjoy a net subsidy of 12.6% (52.6% minus 40%).  Sound fair to you?

In short, whereas capping the tax exclusion even-handedly eliminates the tax subsidy for all workers above a certain premium dollar threshold, the Cadillac tax is far more pernicious–imposing a far heavier burden on low-wage workers than high-wage workers. That is, instead of merely reducing the low-wage worker’s tax subsidy to zero, the Cadillac tax goes overboard by using the tax code to actually penalize the provision of employer-provided health benefits to low wage workers. In contrast, while it obviously reduces the magnitude of the subsidy for high wage workers, it nevertheless leaves in place a net taxpayer subsidy for the identical health coverage for which a low-wage worker would face a tax penalty! Leave aside fairness: does that make any policy sense to you?

The Ultimate Purpose of Obamacare: A Slowed Forced March Into Government-Run Exchanges

In the 2013 video (10:01), Prof. Gruber explicitly acknowledges “most Americans are pretty happy with their health insurance….you don’t get far in America politics by taking away something that makes 250 million people happy to make 50 million other people happy.”  And yet, at its core, Obamacare is designed to do precisely that: to eventually force every American with employer-based coverage onto the Exchanges whether they like it or not.

You may think I’m exaggerating, but don’t take my word for it. First, progressive Obamacare advocates Timothy Jost and Joseph White have conceded that a “major reason why some distinguished economists with whom we have discussed the excise tax endorse the tax is that they see it as a step towards eliminating the employer role in health insurance” (emphasis added).  Second (and more important than intentions in any case), the (now former) Medicare actuary said as much just months after the law was passed. According to a McClatchy report (9.10.10), “CMS chief actuary Richard Foster said he expected “essentially all” Americans to get their private coverage through the exchanges one day.”  This is not some “scientific wild-assed guess:”  it represents the professional judgment of the Medicare actuary based on an analysis of how the inflation-adjustment factor for the Cadillac tax will play out over time.

Under the law, “in 2019, the threshold amounts for the excise tax are increased by the Consumer Price Index (CPI) plus one percentage point. In 2020 and thereafter, the threshold amounts are indexed by just the CPI.” According to the Kaiser Employer Health Benefits Survey, the average cost of family coverage has risen 5.2% annually over the past 4 years (Exhibit 1.1). According the CBO’s latest projections, the CPI will increase by only 2.1% over the next four years (Table 2-3). With such a large gap between the rate at which the cost of employer-provided health coverage is increasing (a reflection of both utilization and price trends) and the rate at which the Cadillac threshold rises, it should be plain to see that a) eventually every employer plan will be subject to the Cadillac tax; and b) for every employer plan that hits the Cadillac tax threshold, the share of plan premiums subject to that tax will steadily grow every year.  It should be quickly evident that for most employees, if the amount to which the Cadillac tax applies exceeds $5000, it would be cheaper for an employer simply to pay the $2000 penalty for not providing mandatory health insurance coverage and instead let workers shop on the Exchanges. That strategy would have the side benefit of letting the lowest paid workers qualify for subsidies whose size would great exceed the tax subsidies provided through the exclusion.  This is why, even though it may take decades to play out, Obamacare can be said to be designed to eradicate employer-provided coverage.

This is yet another instance of the nanny-state mentality that permeates Obamacare. Instead of merely correcting flawed tax policy to make tax incentives neutral between providing employer-provided coverage or letting workers choose their own coverage, Obamacare is using the tax code to engineer the designer’s preferred solution: a world in which employers do not provide health coverage. Let me be clear that I myself actually favor such a world: Avik Roy has repeatedly demonstrated how Switzerland and Singapore (based entirely on individual private insurance) could achieve superior results at far less cost than Obamacare.  But I would never dream of relying on subterfuge to force all Americans into my preferred health system.

In light of the fact that “Gruber has contracts with the federal government and at least eight states totaling about $6 million,” there now are demands that he pay some of that money back. Indeed, Vermont has already stopped payment on one of those contracts. Prof. Gruber evidently will be in the hot seat as he faces chairman Darrell Issa and others on the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform on December 9. But perhaps instead Prof. Gruber deserves thanks and a bonus for single-handedly having done more than any other Obamacare advocate to expose the web of deceptions on which this law was built.[5]

Footnotes

[1] In Jon Gruber’s telling, one leg consists of insurance reforms such as requiring insurers to take all comers–even those with pre-existing conditions–without charging higher premiums to those who are sick. The second leg consists of an individual mandate to make such reforms viable to insurers–since without such a mandate to force the young and healthy to have coverage, the requirement to take all comers without risk-adjusting premiums could quickly lead to a “death spiral.” The third leg are subsidies to make mandated coverage affordable.

[2] Mr. Klein’s language is quite revealing here. It’s not that President Obama couldn’t endorse John McCain’s bold solution to health reform: it’s that he wouldn’t. Recall that candidate Obama was fiercely opposed to the individual mandate: indeed, this was one of the principal issues on which he and Hillary Clinton famously disagreed in primary debates on the matter. Yet once in office, he had no problem whatsoever in literally reversing his position on the matter, ultimately coming around to the view of Jon Gruber and others that such a mandate was one of the essential legs in the three-legged stool logic of how Democrats intended to approach health reform. In short, the president might have elected to go down a bipartisan path on health reform, but deliberately chose not to do so. This is quite different than the conventional wisdom among progressives that Republicans stone-walled the president and never offered any good ideas of their own.

[3] Of course, the Cadillac tax is but one illustration, but Prof. Gruber’s detailed account reveals the mentality behind other taxes in the law. Americans will resist taxes levied directly on themselves, but will passively accept the identical taxes when passed along by businesses that at first glance appear to be paying the tax. I have earlier shown that when we trace back such hidden taxes to the families who ultimately bear them, it turns out that in its first 10 years, Obamacare will force even the lowest cost families to pay roughly $7,000 in higher taxes.  On a similar note, I have pointed out that only 30% of the myriad of Obamacare taxes explicitly target “rich” households.

[4] 15.3% includes both the employee share (7.65%) and companion employer share on grounds that the worker effectively pays for the latter in the form of reduced cash wages even though the employer writes the check.

[5] The caveat “more than any other Obamacare advocate” is important here. Conservative health reformers have been systematically revealing the deceptions embedded in this misguided law since even before its inception (the most noteworthy being Rep. Paul Ryan’s devastating take-down of the Senate bill–the one eventually signed into law–at the Bipartisan Meeting on Health Reform held at Blair House just weeks before the bill was signed into law). It speaks volumes that Rep. Ryan’s 6 minutes of remarks–arguably the clearest, most cogent and memorable of the 6.5 hours of discussion that day–are not included among the 20 clips included in Recommended Highlights on the White House web page devoted to that event. I myself have tried to codify the most egregious deceptions contained in Obamacare.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/obamacares-three-legged-stool-deception-regarding-employer-health-plans/feed/ 0
Unfulfilled political promiseshttp://www.aei.org/publication/unfulfilled-political-promises/ http://www.aei.org/publication/unfulfilled-political-promises/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 14:58:20 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822287 ...]]]> The Obama administration has wisely decided to lower expectations about new health coverage under the Affordable Care Act in the hope that by setting the bar low enough even mediocre enrollment gains become a political victory. Contrary to earlier predictions that the exchanges would enroll 13 million people during the second open enrollment period (which runs for 3 months starting Nov. 15), the administration now says the number is likely to range from 9 to 9.9 million people. Health and Human Services Secretary Sylvia Mathews Burwell said the administration is aiming for 9.1 million paid-up enrollees by the end of 2015.

That can hardly be considered a sign that Obamacare is working. The new enrollment target is just over 2 million greater than the number of people who currently buy their health insurance through the exchanges. It falls far short of the 25 million who, according to the Congressional Budget Office, will have exchange coverage within three years.

This is not surprising. The Affordable Care Act enrollment process is complicated even when the website is working. The second round of sign-ups will be that much harder. The 6.7 million people who ran the gauntlet of the 2014 open enrollment season knew they wanted health coverage and were willing to put up with the frustrations of broken websites and unclear answers.

New enrollees have to be convinced, and the insurance offered this year is as unattractive as ever. Many people will be discouraged by high costs (with deductibles often exceeding $4,000 a year) and not being able to keep their doctors.

To achieve high enrollment numbers, the exchanges must keep those who bought coverage this year as well as attract new customers. The administration announced at the end of June that anyone who had purchased insurance through the exchange could be auto-enrolled in the same plan next year. That reduces disruption in the insurance market and avoids having people lose coverage if they fail to take action. The auto-enrollment option would take pressure off the exchanges if millions of current enrollees decide not to look at the options for next year.

That could be an expensive mistake, and the Department of Health and Human Services has backed off its enthusiasm for auto-enrollment. Unlike employer-sponsored insurance, which uses auto-enrollment routinely for employees, the Affordable Care Act combines health coverage with a welfare program. The exchange subsidy is tied to the second-lowest cost silver plan. Anyone who selected such a plan for this year could find that their plan’s premiums for 2015 have increased 30 percent or more – much higher than that plan’s actual increase. What had been the lowest premium plan after the subsidy this year may become a very pricey option because a competitor did what smart competitors do: undercut the competition.

The health care law has turned the virtues of competition on its head. Plan competition helps lower the market price of insurance, as one would expect. But the complicated subsidy scheme converts those savings into higher costs for many low-income families who are eligible for federal subsidy payments unless they brave the enrollment process again.

[SEE: Editorial Cartoons on the Economy]

As difficult as enrollment has been for the Affordable Care Act, greater troubles are ahead. The individual mandate requires the Internal Revenue Service to withhold refunds from anyone who failed to maintain insurance coverage, starting with 2014 tax returns. The White House might excuse that requirement, at least for this year. Penalizing anyone who did not have insurance because the government’s contractors were unable to create a functioning HealthCare.gov is unfair and poor politics. Dropping enforcement opens the door for Congress to eliminate the penalty altogether, in what could be a bipartisan rebuke of regulatory overreach.

The IRS is also supposed to recover subsidy overpayments from families who underestimated their incomes when they applied for exchange coverage. Instead of a fine of a few hundred dollars for not being insured, some families will be faced with the demand to repay thousands of dollars that they cannot afford. In most cases, these overpayments are simply mistakes, not fraud. Aggressive enforcement will drive more people away from the exchanges. Better to pay the mandate fine than risk IRS collection actions that can ruin credit and destroy credibility.

The employer mandate has proven to be an unworkable and unnecessary mistake. Instead of forcing employers to give generous insurance coverage to their low-wage workers, the mandate is threatening to reduce the number of hours they work below 30 hours. Perversely, workers who most deserve our help will suffer the consequences of lower incomes with no greater access to insurance.

The pending Supreme Court decision on whether the federal exchange can distribute premium subsidies to its enrollees is another threat to the Affordable Care Act. If the court sides with the plaintiffs and agrees that only state exchanges may distribute subsidies, enrollees in the 37 states that rely on the federal exchange will lose their subsidies and enrollment will plummet.

By now it is clear that the political promises made by the president and his supporters could not be fulfilled. You cannot keep your old insurance and you cannot be certain that you can keep your doctor. Insurance costs are not lower, and the new subsidies are being paid through higher taxes and higher private premiums. These are not “glitches.” They are part and parcel of the law.

Over its entire history, a majority of the public has opposed the Affordable Care Act. As the open enrollment season kicked off, a Gallup survey found that only 37 percent of Americans approve of Obamacare. Maybe Americans are not so dumb, after all.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/unfulfilled-political-promises/feed/ 0
Mexico’s security crisis: Will Iguala be a wake-up call?http://www.aei.org/publication/mexicos-security-crisis-will-iguala-wake-call/ http://www.aei.org/publication/mexicos-security-crisis-will-iguala-wake-call/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 13:41:47 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822227 ...]]]> Key points:

  • The kidnapping and probable murder of 43 students at the hands of corrupt local officials and drug gangsters in September is a tragic reminder of persistent criminality and weak government institutions in much of Mexico.
  • Mexican President Enrique Peña Nieto has prioritized key economic reforms over security, and his administration must now deal with instability that undermines his goal to modernize Mexico.
  • The United States should invigorate security cooperation with Mexico to fight crime and secure the border, which will safeguard the long-term benefits of a healthy US-Mexico economic partnership.

 

Read the PDF.

 

Mexico’s democracy, stability, and economy require a collaborative response from all levels of government to quell the wave of recent political unrest and address the underlying causes of insecurity and public dissatisfaction. The current crisis—sparked by national outrage over the September 26 disappearance of 43 students near the town of Iguala in the state of Guerrero—should be a wake-up call for the country.1

The atrocity in Iguala is linked to drug-related corruption and violence, which continues unabated in many areas of the country and has exposed weak state and local governments that enable criminal organizations to operate with virtual impunity in many parts of Mexico.

Widespread public demonstrations and global media coverage since the tragedy are undermining President Enrique Peña Nieto’s effort to portray Mexico as a stable, modernizing nation.2 Furthermore, a pattern of insecurity has evolved into a political crisis that, if not addressed effectively, threatens the governability of the country and the well-being of all Mexicans.

Thus far, Peña Nieto’s perceived ineffective response to the tragedy is fueling public discontent.3 His decision to leave the country to attend the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Summit in China during the growing public protests—and a scandal involving a multibillion-dollar rail construction bid won by a consortium allegedly linked to a $7 million mansion owned by his wife—have stirred doubts about his ability to manage the crisis.4

Two years into his six-year term, Peña Nieto has focused his attention on a series of economic and social reforms that he hopes will make Mexico a more modern nation. Unfortunately, the issues of corruption and insecurity that he consciously underestimated now threaten the stability of the country and the success of reforms that he hopes will be his legacy. His challenge now is to move beyond the political maneuvering in Mexico City and take a stronger hand in governing a country beset by weak institutions, corruption, and organized crime.

Ghosts of Mexico’s Past

In many ways, Mexico’s story is a tale of two countries. One Mexico is undergoing dynamic, positive change that will result in the country finally fulfilling its enormous potential. Particularly in booming urban centers, there is a growing middle class, social mobility, and robust demand for homes and consumer goods.5 Peña Nieto hopes his reforms will attract investment to this dynamic, modern Mexico. But the second Mexico, revealed in recent weeks by the events in Iguala, is hindered by institutions that are too weak and, in some cases, politicians who are too corrupt to impose the rule of law.

The Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) governed Mexico by relying on crony capitalism, quasi-authoritarian political tactics and de facto truces with criminal organizations for more than 70 years. That grip on power was broken from 2000 to 2012 by two successive National Action Party (PAN) presidents. The PRI recovered power with Peña Nieto’s election; however, since his inauguration on December 1, 2012, the young president has advocated sweeping reforms that appeared to break with his party’s corrupt history of defending entrenched interests. He used the political punch of the PRI to push through modernizing reforms that challenged entrenched interests—rewriting tax and education policy and opening up the energy and telecommunications sector.

During his campaign, Peña Nieto also promised a new approach to the confrontational security policy that his predecessor, Felipe Calderón (2006–12), pursued. Calderón launched, for the first time in the country’s history, an aggressive and frontal approach to fighting organized crime. In six years, the bloody confrontation resulted in the loss of some 60,000 Mexican lives, shocking the nation.

Peña Nieto advocated a strategy that favored intelligence over frontal attacks against criminal organizations and focused on dealing with high-impact crimes, such as kidnappings, extortion, and murder.6 Once elected, Peña Nieto made a point of reining in Mexican cooperation with US law enforcement and military. However, it is not clear that he implemented a comprehensive security strategy, preferring to intervene on an ad hoc basis when security crises flared up in various states.

Unfortunately, the toll on citizen security since Peña Nieto took office has been steep. Kidnappings and extortion cases have increased by 27 percent compared to the last administration, according to Mexico’s National Public Security System.7 This criminality has stoked public anxiety about insecurity, which has increased exponentially with the murders in Iguala and the government’s uneven response.

 

Read the full report.

 

Notes

Felipe Trigos, research analyst at Visión Américas LLC, contributed significant sections of this report.

1. In an interview with Christiane Amanpour, Eduardo Medina Mora, Mexico’s ambassador to the United States, noted that Iguala “is a wakeup call for all of us in the shortcomings of our institutional advancement, particularly in states like Guerrero.” See Madalena Araujo, “Mexico Facing ‘Big Political Crisis’ in Aftermath of Student Disappearances, Says Ambassador to U.S.,” CNN, November 12, 2014,

http://amanpour.blogs.cnn.com/2014/11/12/fury-caused-by-disappearance-of-43-students-is-a-big-political-crisis-for-mexico-says-ambassador-to-the-u-s/.

2. Karla Zabludovsky, “Suspected Student Massacre Shocks Violence-Weary Mexico,” Newsweek, October 10, 2014, www.newsweek.com/suspected-student-massacre-shocks-violence-weary-mexico-276561.

3. Jo Tuckman, “President Peña Nieto’s Reputation Founders amid Failure to Find Students,” Guardian, November 3, 2014, www.theguardian.com/world/2014/nov/03/mexico-president-pena-nieto-reputation-founders-failure-find-43-students.

4. Leticia Pineda, “Mexico First Lady’s Mansion Causes Stir,” AFP, November 10, 2014, http://news.yahoo.com/mexico-first-ladys-mansion-causes-stir-002801448.html.

5. Enrique Hernández, “Crece apetito por el sector inmobiliario” [There Is a Growing Appetite for Real Estate], 24 Horas, June 19, 2014, www.24-horas.mx/crece-apetito-por-el-sector-inmobiliario/.

6. Francisco Reséndiz, “Peña Nieto pide más prevención contra el crimen” [Peña Nieto Requests More Crime Prevention], El Universal, February 12, 2013, www.eluniversal.com.mx/notas/902744.html.

7. “Cifras de incidencia delictiva 1997–2014” [Crime Rate Figures, 1997–2014], National Public Security System, www.secretariadoejecutivosnsp.gob.mx/work/models/SecretariadoEjecutivo/Resource/1/1/cifras_publicacion_septiembre14.pdf.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/mexicos-security-crisis-will-iguala-wake-call/feed/ 0
Bee deaths and colony collapse disorder: How Chensheng Lu and his flawed ‘Harvard Study’ endangers beeshttp://www.aei.org/publication/bee-deaths-colony-collapse-disorder-chensheng-lu-flawed-harvard-study-endangers-bees/ http://www.aei.org/publication/bee-deaths-colony-collapse-disorder-chensheng-lu-flawed-harvard-study-endangers-bees/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 13:00:07 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822274 Last week, in Part I of this two part series, “Bee Deaths Mystery Solved? Neonicotinoids (Neonics) May Actually Help Bee Health”, we explored the claims by Harvard School of Public Health researcher Chensheng Lu, heralded by anti-pesticide and anti-GMO advocacy groups, for his research that purportedly proves that the class of chemicals known as neonicotinoids are killing bees and endangering humans. And we saw how many journalists, out of ignorance or for ideological reasons, promote dicey science.

In part II, we examine the specific claims that neonics are responsible for Colony Collapse Disorder—the centerpiece of Lu’s claims. We again see how influential media manipulate quotes and selectively present information to ideologically influence trusting readers. And we look at what might happen if neonics are banned and also their real impact—including intriguing, but incomplete evidence, that when used appropriately the controversial pesticide may actually improve bee health.

A week does not go by without one advocacy group or government official or activist scientist making sensational claims about the supposed catastrophic dangers that neonics supposedly present.

Just last week, for example, advertisements began appearing across Ontario in Canada warning, “neonic pesticides hurt our bees and us,” accompanied by a young boy gazing sadly at a dead bee. They were placed by a fringe advocacy group, the Canadian Association of Physicians for the Environment; its primary funder is David Suzuki, a once prominent but now long retired geneticist who more recently has become known for rants against GMO foods.

That kind of hyperbole, scientists say, obscures the complex story of what’s really happening to bees and why—and the risks that advocacy groups and activist journalists risk of driving science and agricultural regulations into a policy ditch.

This article is available at Science 2.0. 

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/bee-deaths-colony-collapse-disorder-chensheng-lu-flawed-harvard-study-endangers-bees/feed/ 0
European quantitative easing is no panaceahttp://www.aei.org/publication/european-quantitative-easing-panacea/ http://www.aei.org/publication/european-quantitative-easing-panacea/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 12:30:33 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822281 As Europe’s downward economic and political spiral continues, pressure is mounting on the European Central Bank (ECB) to engage in Federal Reserve-style quantitative easing. While such a move is long overdue, it would be a serious mistake to believe that it would in itself extricate the European economy from its present difficult economic circumstances. Rather, for quantitative easing to succeed in Europe, it would need to be accompanied by a combination of fiscal policy stimulus in those eurozone countries that have the fiscal space to do so and of far-reaching growth promoting structural reform in the European economic periphery.

In gauging the likely success of aggressive ECB quantitative easing in Europe, it is important to bear in mind how different the European financial system is from that in the United States. Whereas in the United States around 80 percent of overall lending is intermediated through the securitized credit market, in Europe the bulk of lending is done by banks, with only 20 percent of credit intermediated through the securitized credit market. As such, one must expect that the lower interest rates on corporate bonds that might be expected from quantitative easing would have a very much lesser impact on the European economy than it did on the U.S. economy. By the same token, with much shallower financial markets in Europe than in the United States, one must expect a very much lesser wealth effect in Europe through higher bond and equity prices than was the case in the United States.

There are at least two further reasons to expect that European quantitative easing will not be particularly powerful. The first is that as a result of ample global liquidity, European interest rates are already very low. As a result, there is not much room for European interest rates to fall further. The second reason is that Europe would be engaging in quantitative easing at the very time that the Japanese are very aggressively doing the same thing to weaken the Japanese yen. As a result, while European quantitative easing could be very helpful in cheapening the euro against the U.S. dollar, it is likely that the euro’s depreciation would be fairly limited on an effective basis.

The prospect that quantitative easing in the European context will not be as effective as in the United States is regrettable considering the presently dire straits in which the European economy now finds itself. The European economy has yet to regain its 2008 pre-economic crisis level of activity and it now appears to be on the brink of yet a third economic recession. Equally troubling is the fact that overall European unemployment remains stuck at a stubbornly high level of around 11.5 percent while inflation has now reached a very low level. This has to raise the specter of Europe succumbing to Japanese-style deflation, which is the last thing that its highly indebted economic periphery now needs.

To his credit, in recent months, ECB President Mario Draghi has been alerting European policymakers to the dangers that the European economy now faces, as well as to the limits as to what monetary policy alone can realistically be expected to achieve. He has also been exhorting European policymakers to redouble their efforts at structural reform to promote economic growth, while at the same time urging those European countries with sound public finances to engage in fiscal policy stimulus. One has to hope that the ECB now goes ahead with full-scale quantitative easing without further delay and that European policymakers heed Draghi’s call for fiscal stimulus and structural reform. Since if they do not do so, Europe risks succumbing to Japanese style deflation.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/european-quantitative-easing-panacea/feed/ 0
Nobody is pushing Thomas Piketty’s policies to combat economic inequalityhttp://www.aei.org/publication/nobody-pushing-thomas-pikettys-policies-combat-economic-inequality/ http://www.aei.org/publication/nobody-pushing-thomas-pikettys-policies-combat-economic-inequality/#comments Mon, 24 Nov 2014 10:00:51 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822270 Last spring, you may remember, the French economist Thomas Piketty was all the rage in certain enlightened circles. His book Capital shot up to the number one spot on bestseller lists, and many economists praised his statistics showing increased income and wealth inequality. Piketty argued that, absent a world war, returns to capital will exceed economic growth, inevitably producing growing inequality in the twenty-first century.

There are problems with Piketty’s — or anyone else’s — statistics. Reliance on U.S. income tax returns overlooks the fact that tax cuts encourage people to realize income and misses non-taxable income like welfare and Social Security payments.

Still, there has clearly been a boom in the incomes and wealth of the top 1 percent here and worldwide. Piketty sees this as a threat to democracy. Liberal economists and pundits hoped that his revelations would finally get politicians to support policies like Piketty’s 80 percent tax rate on high incomes and progressive tax on great wealth — and get the masses to vote for them.

So far it hasn’t happened here or just about anywhere.

You didn’t see any campaign ads calling for Piketty taxes this fall. You didn’t even see any ads hailing Democrats for having raised taxes on high earners in early 2013. Democratic candidates in seriously contested races didn’t come close to advocating such policies.

You may have heard some Democrats bemoaning income inequality. The idea that the rich get richer while everyone else doesn’t gets pretty wide agreement in the polls. So does the Democrats’ one redistributionist policy — raising the minimum wage.

As a policy to address inequality, though, it’s rather pathetic. About half of minimum wage earners are not in the lowest fifth households in income. Even fewer are their own household’s primary earner. Almost all economists agree that when the minimum wage is raised, some employees lose their jobs.

It is only slightly hyperbolic to say that an increased minimum wage is a transfer of income from fast food customers to fast food workers minus those who are replaced by kiosks. That’s not a very effective way to sock it to the top 1 percent.

Even after the election, some Democrats argue that they didn’t hit the issue hard enough. One Democrat’s advice to President Obama, according to Politico, “is focus on income inequality, and talk about and propose things, and just be a fierce advocate of addressing the economic divide. That will leave people after two years saying the Democratic party really stands for something.”

“Propose things” — but what? A recent Congressional Budget Office report shows that when you measure federal taxes paid minus federal transfers received (welfare, food stamps, Social Security, etc.), the top 20 percent of earners pay an average of $46,500. The next 20 percent pay an average of $700. The bottom three-fifths get back more than they pay. Plus, the U.S. already relies more heavily on the income tax for revenues than any other advanced economy nation.

In other words, America already has lots of economic redistribution. American voters evidently sense that more redistribution more would sap economic growth. They’re willing to throw a little to minimum wage earners, but they don’t want to kill the geese laying the golden eggs.

Americans are not alone in feeling that way. You don’t see much demand for Piketty policies in other countries either.

Even in Brazil, with near-zero growth and much greater inequality than the U.S., incumbent President Dilma Rousseff saw her percentage slip from 56 percent in 2010 to 52 percent this October.

In Britain, facing an election next May, there are calls within the Labour party to oust leader Ed Miliband, who has called for freezing energy prices and a tax on “mansions” which would hit Londoners hard.

Piketty confesses he has seldom left Paris in his adult years. But even there his policies are in trouble. The job approval of Socialist President François Hollande, who imposed a top income tax rate of 75 percent, currently hovers just above 10 percent.

Politicians opposing massive economic redistribution have a hard time coming up with appealing rhetoric. But there seems to be something more powerful working in their favor — a widespread if unspoken understanding that government attempts to “spread the wealth around” (as candidate Obama once told Joe the Plumber) tend to destroy it instead.

Piketty has sold a lot of books. But his policies don’t seem to be selling well anywhere.

Michael Barone is a senior political columnist for the Washington Examiner. This column is reprinted with permission from washingtonexaminer.com.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/nobody-pushing-thomas-pikettys-policies-combat-economic-inequality/feed/ 0
The possibility of a government shutdown is very high: Ornstein on MSNBC’s ‘Office Politics’http://www.aei.org/press/possibility-government-shutdown-high-ornstein-msnbcs-office-politics/ http://www.aei.org/press/possibility-government-shutdown-high-ornstein-msnbcs-office-politics/#comments Sat, 22 Nov 2014 12:30:24 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=press&p=822296 http://www.aei.org/press/possibility-government-shutdown-high-ornstein-msnbcs-office-politics/feed/ 0 An amazing chart of an amazing job-creating state; we owe a debt of gratitude to ‘Saudi Texas’ and the shale boomhttp://www.aei.org/publication/822253/ http://www.aei.org/publication/822253/#comments Sat, 22 Nov 2014 00:22:24 +0000 http://www.aei.org/?post_type=publication&p=822253 ...]]]> The chart above shows a most amazing economic phenomenon: Since December 2007 when the Great Recession started, Texas civilian employment has increased by 12.4% and by more than 1.36 million jobs, from just over 11 million jobs in December 2007 to 12.37 million in October of this year (see blue line in chart). In contrast, civilian employment in the other 49 states without Texas is still 0.26% and more than 350,000 jobs below the December 2007 level (see red line in chart) — there were 134.9 million non-Texas jobs in October vs. 135.26 million in December 2007.

It’s also important to note that while job growth in Texas slowed considerably in 2008 and 2009 due to the recession, the level of civilian employment in Texas never fell below its pre-recessionary, December 2007 level. Also, while Texas was able to actually increase jobs slightly even during the depths of the recession in 2008 and 2009, the US labor market minus Texas experienced a stunning loss of 8.374 million jobs (a percentage drop of 6.2%) in the two year period between December 2007 and December 2009.

In another job-related milestone for Texas, the BLS reported today that annual payroll employment in Texas increased in October by more than 400,000 jobs from a year ago for the third straight month, and established a new all-time state record for job growth over a 12-month period with a 421,900 gain from October 2013. Over the last year, Texas has added more than 1,600 new jobs every business day – a hiring rate of more than 200 jobs every hour! Also, Texas’s annual job gain of 421,900 through October represented 16% of the country’s 2.643 million increase in nonfarm payroll employment over that period, even though Texas’s population is only 8.4% of the US total. In percentage terms, Texas payrolls increased by 3.74% over the last 12 months, almost double the 1.93% growth in US payroll employment.

The chart and data tell a powerful and remarkable story of job creation in the Lone Star State of more than 1.36 million new jobs added since the start of the Great Recession, compared to a net deficit of 354,000 jobs for the other 49 states combined. Much of the economic success of Texas in recent years that has fueled job creation in the state is a direct result of the shale oil and gas boom taking place in areas like the Permian Basin in west Texas (1.8 million barrels of oil per day) and the Eagle Ford in south central Texas (1.6 million barrels per day). Texas is now producing almost 37% of America’s total crude oil production, and as a separate country would be the world’s 8th largest oil-producer. Further, Texas has done a great job of attracting businesses like Toyota because of the state’s “employer-friendly combination of low taxes, fair courts, smart regulations and world-class workforce.”

Bottom Line: The country, the president, and all of us individually owe a huge debt of gratitude to the state of Texas and to the oil and gas industry for helping support the US economy during and after the Great Recession. Without the energy-driven economic stimulus from the fracking revolution, and without the gusher of jobs in the state of Texas, there’s no question that the Great Recession would have been much worse and lasted much longer, and the jobs picture today would be much bleaker. The chart above helps to illustrate how important the state of “Saudi Texas” is to the US labor market and economy. Thanks largely to the Lone Star State, the US has finally gained back all of the jobs lost during the Great Recession – September and October this year have been the only two months since 2007 that civilian employment in the US surpassed the pre-recession jobs peak. God Bless Texas.

]]>
http://www.aei.org/publication/822253/feed/ 22